next up previous
Next: About this document ...

CLASS #17: POLICY GAMES: MONETARY POLICY AND THE UNEMPLOYMENT/INFLATION TRADE OFF
There is always a temporary tradeoff between inflation and unemployment; there is no permanent tradeoff. The temporary tradeoff comes not from inflation per se, but from unanticipated inflation, which generally means, from a rising rate of inflation.
Milton Friedman
The Phillips Curve: an empirical regularity
The Expectations Augmented Phillips Curve
From the misperception theory:

\begin{displaymath}\ln{Y_t}=\ln{\bar{Y}}+a(\ln{P_t}-\ln{P_t^e})\end{displaymath}

Let us add and subtract $\ln{P_{t-1}}$ from the right hand side:

\begin{displaymath}\ln{Y_t}=\ln{\bar{Y}}+a(\ln{P_t}-\ln{P_{t-1}}-(\ln{P_t^e}-\ln{P_{t-1}}))=\end{displaymath}


\begin{displaymath}=\ln{\bar{Y}}+a(\pi_t-\pi_t^e)\end{displaymath}

and let us remember Okun's Law:

\begin{displaymath}\ln{Y_t}-\ln{\bar{Y}}=-b(u_t-\bar{u})\end{displaymath}

We obtain a ``theoretical version" of the Phillips curve:

\begin{displaymath}u_t-\bar{u}=-\theta(\pi_t-\pi_t^e)\end{displaymath}

where $\theta=\frac{a}{b}.$
Policy Games
Let us call $y=\ln(Y)$ and introduce a disturbance e in the aggregate supply equation:

\begin{displaymath}y=\bar{y}+a(\pi-\pi^e)+e\end{displaymath}

Let us postulate the following link between inflation and the growth rate of money supply:

\begin{displaymath}\pi=\mu+v\end{displaymath}

where v is a -velocity- disturbance in the equation. Lets us say that the Central Bank wants to maximize output (say, for political economy reasons) and minimize inflation, that is, its objective function is:

\begin{displaymath}max_\mu \lambda(y-\bar{y})-\frac12 \pi^2\end{displaymath}

Of course, the Central Bank takes into account that there is something called Phillips curve out there, so that it cannot minimize both. After substituting the constraint into the objective function we obtain:

\begin{displaymath}max_\mu \lambda(a(\mu+v-\pi^e)+e)-\frac12 (\mu+v)^2\end{displaymath}

The timing of events is as follows: The private sector is contracting their wages, debt contracts... they want to predict inflation as good as they can, otherwise it is going to be bad news for somebody (for workers if inflation is above expectations, for entrepreneurs is inflation is below expectations). Say that the Central Bank could commit to an inflation rate $\pi^c$, announce it today, and have the public believe it.
Since the public is forming expectations on the basis of the Central Bank's announcement, it is clear that $\pi_t^e=\mu^c$. So nobody is fooled, and the Central Bank cannot ``run the Phillips curve".
The objective function becomes:

\begin{displaymath}max_\mu \lambda(av+e)-\frac12 (\mu^c+v)^2\end{displaymath}

Of course, the best thing to do for the Central Bank is to set $\mu^c=0$, so at least it has zero inflation, even if it has no gain on the unemployment side.
Expected utility is:

\begin{displaymath}E(U)=-\frac12 \sigma^2_v\end{displaymath}

Let us consider the more realistic case where the Central Bank cannot commit itself (discretionary policy). Once the private sector has formed the inflationary expectations $\pi_t^e$, the Central Bank takes them as given as chooses $\mu$ so to maximize its objective function.
The first order condition is:

\begin{displaymath}a\lambda-\mu=0\end{displaymath}

which delivers:

\begin{displaymath}\mu=a\lambda\end{displaymath}

Actual inflation will then be:

\begin{displaymath}\pi=a\lambda+v\end{displaymath}

Agents understand the model and set expectations equal to:

\begin{displaymath}\pi^e=a\lambda\end{displaymath}

What is the result?

 
next up previous
Next: About this document ...
Marco Del Negro
2000-05-01